Interpreting the results of a 3x3 Nash Mixed Strategies Equilibrium












0












$begingroup$


I've got a 3x3 Nash game cube I'm trying to interpret. The decimals below represent the number of times a player 'wins' against the other player.



             A             B             C
A 0.722,0.278 0.722, 0.278 0.800, 0.200
B 0.750, 0.250 0.780, 0.220 0.875, 0.125
C 0.286, 0.714 0.200, 0.800 1.000, 0.000


When I run this through the method for solving 3x3 Nash squares, this is the equation I use:



 A->B: (p+q+(1-p-q) = p1 + q1 + (1-p1-q1))
B->C: (p1+q1+(1-p1-q1) = p2 + q2 + (1-p2-q2))


and I substitute p from one into the other to find q.



The result I get for the horizontal player, from the above square however, don't make sense:



   Horizontal Player
A = 0.07460291360037259
B = 0.18149088118987192
C = 0.7439062052097555


This would indicate that the horizontal player should play 75% of the time. Yet, strategy B clearly produces better results for the horizontal player consistently. Am I interpreting this correctly? It is possible I made a programming error, but the Vertical Player makes sense:



  Vertical Player
A = 0.14930944382232172
B = 1.1347517730496453
C = -0.28406121687196695


It's gobbledy gook. But just visually analyzing the square indicates that B is the best strategy.



Any feedback you can provide is much appreciated.










share|cite|improve this question









$endgroup$












  • $begingroup$
    Doing the expected value calculation can sometimes produce negative "probabilities" if the game has a pure strategy equilibrium. Your game has one at B,A since the payoff to left player is the highest in the column, and the payoff to either player is highest in the row.
    $endgroup$
    – dbx
    Dec 25 '18 at 3:18










  • $begingroup$
    Thanks! That makes a lot of sense, actually. These are strategies and C is the weakest. When I apply the rule you described to all of the different groupings of the data, the pure strategies most often involve C because the other two essentially take advantage of it. Is there anything to be gleaned from the fact that the row player produces a mixed strategies equilibrium? Or, does that only have meaning if the column player also has a mixed strategy?
    $endgroup$
    – Jess Behrens
    Dec 25 '18 at 6:47


















0












$begingroup$


I've got a 3x3 Nash game cube I'm trying to interpret. The decimals below represent the number of times a player 'wins' against the other player.



             A             B             C
A 0.722,0.278 0.722, 0.278 0.800, 0.200
B 0.750, 0.250 0.780, 0.220 0.875, 0.125
C 0.286, 0.714 0.200, 0.800 1.000, 0.000


When I run this through the method for solving 3x3 Nash squares, this is the equation I use:



 A->B: (p+q+(1-p-q) = p1 + q1 + (1-p1-q1))
B->C: (p1+q1+(1-p1-q1) = p2 + q2 + (1-p2-q2))


and I substitute p from one into the other to find q.



The result I get for the horizontal player, from the above square however, don't make sense:



   Horizontal Player
A = 0.07460291360037259
B = 0.18149088118987192
C = 0.7439062052097555


This would indicate that the horizontal player should play 75% of the time. Yet, strategy B clearly produces better results for the horizontal player consistently. Am I interpreting this correctly? It is possible I made a programming error, but the Vertical Player makes sense:



  Vertical Player
A = 0.14930944382232172
B = 1.1347517730496453
C = -0.28406121687196695


It's gobbledy gook. But just visually analyzing the square indicates that B is the best strategy.



Any feedback you can provide is much appreciated.










share|cite|improve this question









$endgroup$












  • $begingroup$
    Doing the expected value calculation can sometimes produce negative "probabilities" if the game has a pure strategy equilibrium. Your game has one at B,A since the payoff to left player is the highest in the column, and the payoff to either player is highest in the row.
    $endgroup$
    – dbx
    Dec 25 '18 at 3:18










  • $begingroup$
    Thanks! That makes a lot of sense, actually. These are strategies and C is the weakest. When I apply the rule you described to all of the different groupings of the data, the pure strategies most often involve C because the other two essentially take advantage of it. Is there anything to be gleaned from the fact that the row player produces a mixed strategies equilibrium? Or, does that only have meaning if the column player also has a mixed strategy?
    $endgroup$
    – Jess Behrens
    Dec 25 '18 at 6:47
















0












0








0





$begingroup$


I've got a 3x3 Nash game cube I'm trying to interpret. The decimals below represent the number of times a player 'wins' against the other player.



             A             B             C
A 0.722,0.278 0.722, 0.278 0.800, 0.200
B 0.750, 0.250 0.780, 0.220 0.875, 0.125
C 0.286, 0.714 0.200, 0.800 1.000, 0.000


When I run this through the method for solving 3x3 Nash squares, this is the equation I use:



 A->B: (p+q+(1-p-q) = p1 + q1 + (1-p1-q1))
B->C: (p1+q1+(1-p1-q1) = p2 + q2 + (1-p2-q2))


and I substitute p from one into the other to find q.



The result I get for the horizontal player, from the above square however, don't make sense:



   Horizontal Player
A = 0.07460291360037259
B = 0.18149088118987192
C = 0.7439062052097555


This would indicate that the horizontal player should play 75% of the time. Yet, strategy B clearly produces better results for the horizontal player consistently. Am I interpreting this correctly? It is possible I made a programming error, but the Vertical Player makes sense:



  Vertical Player
A = 0.14930944382232172
B = 1.1347517730496453
C = -0.28406121687196695


It's gobbledy gook. But just visually analyzing the square indicates that B is the best strategy.



Any feedback you can provide is much appreciated.










share|cite|improve this question









$endgroup$




I've got a 3x3 Nash game cube I'm trying to interpret. The decimals below represent the number of times a player 'wins' against the other player.



             A             B             C
A 0.722,0.278 0.722, 0.278 0.800, 0.200
B 0.750, 0.250 0.780, 0.220 0.875, 0.125
C 0.286, 0.714 0.200, 0.800 1.000, 0.000


When I run this through the method for solving 3x3 Nash squares, this is the equation I use:



 A->B: (p+q+(1-p-q) = p1 + q1 + (1-p1-q1))
B->C: (p1+q1+(1-p1-q1) = p2 + q2 + (1-p2-q2))


and I substitute p from one into the other to find q.



The result I get for the horizontal player, from the above square however, don't make sense:



   Horizontal Player
A = 0.07460291360037259
B = 0.18149088118987192
C = 0.7439062052097555


This would indicate that the horizontal player should play 75% of the time. Yet, strategy B clearly produces better results for the horizontal player consistently. Am I interpreting this correctly? It is possible I made a programming error, but the Vertical Player makes sense:



  Vertical Player
A = 0.14930944382232172
B = 1.1347517730496453
C = -0.28406121687196695


It's gobbledy gook. But just visually analyzing the square indicates that B is the best strategy.



Any feedback you can provide is much appreciated.







nash-equilibrium






share|cite|improve this question













share|cite|improve this question











share|cite|improve this question




share|cite|improve this question










asked Dec 25 '18 at 0:48









Jess BehrensJess Behrens

1




1












  • $begingroup$
    Doing the expected value calculation can sometimes produce negative "probabilities" if the game has a pure strategy equilibrium. Your game has one at B,A since the payoff to left player is the highest in the column, and the payoff to either player is highest in the row.
    $endgroup$
    – dbx
    Dec 25 '18 at 3:18










  • $begingroup$
    Thanks! That makes a lot of sense, actually. These are strategies and C is the weakest. When I apply the rule you described to all of the different groupings of the data, the pure strategies most often involve C because the other two essentially take advantage of it. Is there anything to be gleaned from the fact that the row player produces a mixed strategies equilibrium? Or, does that only have meaning if the column player also has a mixed strategy?
    $endgroup$
    – Jess Behrens
    Dec 25 '18 at 6:47




















  • $begingroup$
    Doing the expected value calculation can sometimes produce negative "probabilities" if the game has a pure strategy equilibrium. Your game has one at B,A since the payoff to left player is the highest in the column, and the payoff to either player is highest in the row.
    $endgroup$
    – dbx
    Dec 25 '18 at 3:18










  • $begingroup$
    Thanks! That makes a lot of sense, actually. These are strategies and C is the weakest. When I apply the rule you described to all of the different groupings of the data, the pure strategies most often involve C because the other two essentially take advantage of it. Is there anything to be gleaned from the fact that the row player produces a mixed strategies equilibrium? Or, does that only have meaning if the column player also has a mixed strategy?
    $endgroup$
    – Jess Behrens
    Dec 25 '18 at 6:47


















$begingroup$
Doing the expected value calculation can sometimes produce negative "probabilities" if the game has a pure strategy equilibrium. Your game has one at B,A since the payoff to left player is the highest in the column, and the payoff to either player is highest in the row.
$endgroup$
– dbx
Dec 25 '18 at 3:18




$begingroup$
Doing the expected value calculation can sometimes produce negative "probabilities" if the game has a pure strategy equilibrium. Your game has one at B,A since the payoff to left player is the highest in the column, and the payoff to either player is highest in the row.
$endgroup$
– dbx
Dec 25 '18 at 3:18












$begingroup$
Thanks! That makes a lot of sense, actually. These are strategies and C is the weakest. When I apply the rule you described to all of the different groupings of the data, the pure strategies most often involve C because the other two essentially take advantage of it. Is there anything to be gleaned from the fact that the row player produces a mixed strategies equilibrium? Or, does that only have meaning if the column player also has a mixed strategy?
$endgroup$
– Jess Behrens
Dec 25 '18 at 6:47






$begingroup$
Thanks! That makes a lot of sense, actually. These are strategies and C is the weakest. When I apply the rule you described to all of the different groupings of the data, the pure strategies most often involve C because the other two essentially take advantage of it. Is there anything to be gleaned from the fact that the row player produces a mixed strategies equilibrium? Or, does that only have meaning if the column player also has a mixed strategy?
$endgroup$
– Jess Behrens
Dec 25 '18 at 6:47












0






active

oldest

votes











Your Answer





StackExchange.ifUsing("editor", function () {
return StackExchange.using("mathjaxEditing", function () {
StackExchange.MarkdownEditor.creationCallbacks.add(function (editor, postfix) {
StackExchange.mathjaxEditing.prepareWmdForMathJax(editor, postfix, [["$", "$"], ["\\(","\\)"]]);
});
});
}, "mathjax-editing");

StackExchange.ready(function() {
var channelOptions = {
tags: "".split(" "),
id: "69"
};
initTagRenderer("".split(" "), "".split(" "), channelOptions);

StackExchange.using("externalEditor", function() {
// Have to fire editor after snippets, if snippets enabled
if (StackExchange.settings.snippets.snippetsEnabled) {
StackExchange.using("snippets", function() {
createEditor();
});
}
else {
createEditor();
}
});

function createEditor() {
StackExchange.prepareEditor({
heartbeatType: 'answer',
autoActivateHeartbeat: false,
convertImagesToLinks: true,
noModals: true,
showLowRepImageUploadWarning: true,
reputationToPostImages: 10,
bindNavPrevention: true,
postfix: "",
imageUploader: {
brandingHtml: "Powered by u003ca class="icon-imgur-white" href="https://imgur.com/"u003eu003c/au003e",
contentPolicyHtml: "User contributions licensed under u003ca href="https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-sa/3.0/"u003ecc by-sa 3.0 with attribution requiredu003c/au003e u003ca href="https://stackoverflow.com/legal/content-policy"u003e(content policy)u003c/au003e",
allowUrls: true
},
noCode: true, onDemand: true,
discardSelector: ".discard-answer"
,immediatelyShowMarkdownHelp:true
});


}
});














draft saved

draft discarded


















StackExchange.ready(
function () {
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3051751%2finterpreting-the-results-of-a-3x3-nash-mixed-strategies-equilibrium%23new-answer', 'question_page');
}
);

Post as a guest















Required, but never shown

























0






active

oldest

votes








0






active

oldest

votes









active

oldest

votes






active

oldest

votes
















draft saved

draft discarded




















































Thanks for contributing an answer to Mathematics Stack Exchange!


  • Please be sure to answer the question. Provide details and share your research!

But avoid



  • Asking for help, clarification, or responding to other answers.

  • Making statements based on opinion; back them up with references or personal experience.


Use MathJax to format equations. MathJax reference.


To learn more, see our tips on writing great answers.




draft saved


draft discarded














StackExchange.ready(
function () {
StackExchange.openid.initPostLogin('.new-post-login', 'https%3a%2f%2fmath.stackexchange.com%2fquestions%2f3051751%2finterpreting-the-results-of-a-3x3-nash-mixed-strategies-equilibrium%23new-answer', 'question_page');
}
);

Post as a guest















Required, but never shown





















































Required, but never shown














Required, but never shown












Required, but never shown







Required, but never shown

































Required, but never shown














Required, but never shown












Required, but never shown







Required, but never shown







Popular posts from this blog

Wiesbaden

Marschland

Dieringhausen